|
11/26 |
2007/6/11-13 [Politics/Domestic/Crime] UID:46915 Activity:high 57%like:46907 |
6/11 Death penalty deters homicide (AP story) http://www.star-telegram.com/national_news/story/132840.html (If you have comments on the study, make your comments below, don't alter the OP.) \_ Oh but this is so politically incorrect ...... \_ `The studies' conclusions drew a philosophical response from a well-known liberal law professor and death penalty critic, Cass Sunstein ...... "Abolitionists or others, like me, who are skeptical about the death penalty haven't given adequate consideration to the possibility that innocent life is saved by the death penalty."' Mocan: "The results are robust, they don't really go away," he said. "I oppose the death penalty. But my results show that the death penalty [deters], What am I going to do, hide them?" \_ http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=928649 "We address this error by focusing on the subset of homicides that have been defined statutorily as capital-eligible to provide a more sensitive indicator of the deterrent effects of the death penalty. We use a public-use data archive based on police descriptions of homicides from 1976-2003 to construct rates of potentially death-eligible killings. We estimate that less than 25% of total criminal homicides are eligible for the capital sanction under the range of current state statutes. We find no changes over time in the rate of these capital-eligible homicides in death penalty states, despite fluctuations in capital punishment over time. " \_ The vast command of homicide law possessed by an average potential murderer combined with these findings is sure to debunk the study in OP's link! A more serious objection would be to point out that no purely statistical study can determine effect, period. -- ilyas \_ The problem is that the presentation of the study if used as a pro-death penalty argument neglects two major factors: first, the objective logistical impossibility of ensuring that no innocent persons are executed, and the entirely subjective question as to whether it's right or wrong for a collective to decide on life or death. -John pro-death penalty argument neglects two major factors: first, the objective logistical impossibility of ensuring that no innocent persons are executed, and the entirely subjective question as to whether it's right or wrong for a collective to decide on life or death. -John \_ Those are legitimate issues to debate. However, critics commonly say of the death penalty that it's not a deterrent. I'd be interested to see how this compares to (say) life without parole (which is a sentence I'm increasingly seeing as favorable to the death penalty). -emarkp \_ I personally feel the "death penalty as a deterrent" point is as irrelevant as the "death penalty as a disposal" or "death penalty as a punishment" arguments. That was kind of what I was getting at. -JOhn \_ If you don't believe in the DP, then you won't find any pro-DP points with merit. Just like abortion, God existing/religion, evolution, and gun control, some issues are not determined by logic, reason, statistics, facts, etc but by people's personal philosophies and feelings. And that is ok. We are not robots or computers and should not always guide or measure society by pure logic and reason. \- that's not true. i went from pro-DP to anti. although i wasnt very strong pro and an not strong-anti, for example i think while it is on the books, it's resonable to ask for it in some cases, like timothy mcveigh. i think it is too bad robert hanssen and and alderidge ames didnt get the death penalty. if it was more fairly applied, i might have switched back to pro. my position: it is ok per constitution. i dont think the cost of DP is that much of an issue. it's worth researching the deterrence question ... like maybe we can have DP for while collar crime above $10m and see if it is detweent ... and i suppose society has see if it is deterent ... and i suppose society has the right to "take life". but the "machinery of death" runs in a really disturbing way ... like non- functioning electric chairs, leathal injections incompetently administered to more subtle things like statistical biases of death certified juries. but by far the biggest thing is the disparate application. it's like talking about the draft or school vouchers: the details matter. i were king i would put many people to death. and society would be better off for it ... at least for the first 6mos. then it might get out of control. french rev and all that. \_ I think your last line is the real issue. What is a true DP offense? Who decides? How can we be sure? I'm perfectly ok with most folks getting life in prison because there are too many times where a death row inmate is found innocent, often after years in prison. But I've got no problem putting someone like Manson and numerous others where there can be no doubt and no concept of rehabilitation on the chair and frying them. And yes I agree the chairs should work, procedures should be followed, etc, but if it takes a few extra zots to off a Charles Manson or he goes out suffering I'm not going to shed any tears over it. \_ And this is why I'm neither Pro- or Anti-DP: I view it as a tool, and as such I want it to work work reliably and well when needed, but I don't want it applied to every situation (cf. Maslow, hammer, nails). I'm not pro- or anti-screwdrivers, either. --erikred |
11/26 |
|
www.star-telegram.com/national_news/story/132840.html Graph: Executions down THE ASSOCIATED PRESS Graph: Executions down Anti-death penalty forces have gained momentum in the past few years, with a moratorium in Illinois, court disputes over lethal injection in more than a half-dozen states and progress toward outright abolishment in New Jersey. What gets little notice, however, is a series of academic studies over the last half-dozen years that claim to settle a once hotly debated argument: whether the death penalty acts as a deterrent to murder. They say between three and 18 lives would be saved by the execution of each convicted killer. The reports have horrified death penalty opponents and some scientists, who vigorously question the data and their implications. So far, the studies have had little effect on public policy. New Jersey's commission on the death penalty this year dismissed the body of knowledge on deterrence as "inconclusive." But the ferocious argument in academic circles could eventually spread to a wider audience. There is no question about it," said Naci Mocan, an economics professor at the University of Colorado at Denver, who has done some of the research. Deterrent effects A 2003 study Mocan co-wrote, and a 2006 study that re-examined the data, said that each execution results in five fewer homicides and that commuting a death sentence means five more. "The results are robust, they don't really go away," he said. Statistical studies like his are among a dozen papers since 2001 that capital punishment has deterrent effects. They all explore the same basic theory: If the cost of something (be it the purchase of an apple or the act of killing someone) becomes too high, people will change their behavior (forgo apples or shy from murder). In 2005, there were 16,692 cases of murder and nonnegligent manslaughter nationally. Texas, which is responsible for two-thirds of all executions, had its 15th execution Wednesday. Response The studies' conclusions drew a philosophical response from a well-known liberal law professor and death penalty critic, Cass Sunstein of the University of Chicago. In 2005, he co-wrote a paper titled Is Capital Punishment Morally Required? "If it's the case that executing murderers prevents the execution of innocents by murderers, then the moral evaluation is not simple," he told The Associated Press. "Abolitionists or others, like me, who are skeptical about the death penalty haven't given adequate consideration to the possibility that innocent life is saved by the death penalty." Sunstein said that moral questions aside, the data need more study. Some critics say that the deterrent-supporting studies made profound mistakes in their methodology, so their results are untrustworthy. One critic argues that the studies wrongly count all homicides, rather than just those homicides where a conviction could bring the death penalty. And several argue that there are simply too few executions each year in the United States to make a judgment. "We just don't have enough data to say anything," said Justin Wolfers, an economist at the Wharton School of Business who last year co-wrote a sweeping critique of several studies and said they were "flimsy" and appeared in "second-tier journals." This report includes information from the Star-Telegram archives. Death penalty To explore the question of whether the death penalty deters homicide, researchers look at executions and homicides, by year, state or county, trying to tease out the effect of the death penalty on homicides by accounting for other factors, such as unemployment data and per capita income, the probabilities of arrest and conviction, and more. Among the conclusions: A 2003 nationwide study by professors at Emory University says each execution deters an average of 18 murders. Other studies have estimated deterred murders per execution at three, five and 14. A 2006 study by professors at the University of Houston said the Illinois moratorium on executions in 2000 led to 150 additional homicides over the next four years. A 2004 study by an Emory University professor said that speeding up executions would strengthen the deterrent effect: For every 275 years cut from time spent on Death Row, one murder would be prevented. |
papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=928649 Texas Law Review, Forthcoming Abstract: Both legal scholars and social scientists have leveraged new research evidence on the deterrent effects of the death penalty into calls for more executions that they claim will save lives and new rules to remove procedural roadblocks and hasten executions. However, the use of total intentional homicides to estimate deterrence is a recurring aggregation error in the death penalty debate in the US: by studying whether executions and death sentences affect all homicides, these studies fail to identify a more plausible target of deterrence - namely, those homicides that are punishable by death. By broadening the targets of deterrence, these studies overestimate the number of murders that are averted by the threat of execution. We address this error by focusing on the subset of homicides that have been defined statutorily as capital-eligible to provide a more sensitive indicator of the deterrent effects of the death penalty. We use a public-use data archive based on police descriptions of homicides from 1976-2003 to construct rates of potentially death-eligible killings. We estimate that less than 25% of total criminal homicides are eligible for the capital sanction under the range of current state statutes. We find no changes over time in the rate of these capital-eligible homicides in death penalty states, despite fluctuations in capital punishment over time. Nor are there differences capital-eligible homicides between death penalty and non-death penalty states. We find similar flat trends in Texas, and also in Harris County, the county that supplies the most death cases in Texas. Using hierarchical regression models to fit growth curve trajectories over time and with a rich set of covariates that account for competing influences on homicide rates, we find no deterrent effects either from the presence of the death penalty or from variation over time in the dosage of any of its components in the states. Similar models for Texas counties produced identical results. The results show that none of the distinctive patterns one might expect from marginal death penalty deterrence can be found in the three decades since Gregg. Where the risk of execution goes up in a death penalty state, the death-eligible cases where that risk should make a difference decline no more than the non-death-eligible cases, nor is the proportion of all homicides that risk a capital sanction in death states any smaller in those states than it is in states without any death penalty. The rate of capital-eligible homicides is insensitive over time to variations in the incidence of executions or to the large swings from one decade to the next in the number or rate of non-death-eligible killings. Our search for death penalty deterrence where it should be a strong influence on homicide rates has produced consistent results: the marginal deterrent effect of the threat or example of execution on those cases at risk for such punishment is invisible. Accepted Paper Series Suggested Citation Fagan, Jeffrey, Zimring, Franklin E and Geller, Amanda B, "Capital Punishment and Capital Murder: Market Share and the Deterrent Effects of the Death Penalty" . |